Skip to main content
  • Original article
  • Open access
  • Published:

Analysing Gordon’s trade-off by adapting Thurow’s approach of pure public good to the German energy sector

Abstract

Background

We analyse Gordon’s trade-off by adapting Thurow’s approach of pure public good using the example of the German energy sector which is in a transition process to a low-carbon sustainable energy system (Energiewende). The income distribution and the energy expenditures of households are interpreted as public goods. Their distribution is measured with the Atkinson index, which determines how the quality of life, as measured in income and energy expenditures, is distributed among society.

Methods

We use the disaggregated consumption and income for 39.409 million German households. Our socio-economic analysis focuses on six household types.

Results

Our analysis shows that among German households, energy expenditures are more equally distributed than private consumption in general and income. The rather (but by far not completely) equal distribution of energy expenditures confirms Smil’s finding that energy is the universal currency (Sen, On Economic Inequality, 1973) for people’s welfare and can be seen as an indicator of the basic needs of households irrespective of household income. Nevertheless, low-income households have to spend a higher share of their income on energy to avoid energy poverty. Further price increases could lead to an unequal distribution and rising energy poverty.

Conclusions

The socio‐economic conditions of society and its energy sector have to be addressed in a transition processes. Energy poverty constitutes an infringement of the sustainability concept. If society does not take distributional effects into account, the transition process itself could be jeopardized.

Background

Sustainable development is a process in which society and political decision makers have to balance ecological, economic, and social targets. Equal rights and equality in terms of “equivalent living conditions” (Article 74 German constitutional law) are key elements of the social pillar of sustainability.

Gordon’s trade-off

Modern societies are confronted with Gordon’sFootnote 1 trade-off [14], that is to say, their democratic constitutions guarantee all citizens the same political rights and obligations [27]. However, this democratic guarantee of equality is contrasted with economic inequality as the result of economic market forces which produce unequal income, consumption opportunities, and life prospects [14, 29]. Individuals have the same political rights, but their social participation opportunities correlate not only with these rights but also with their individual success in economic processes [7, 14]. Individuals are affected by two institutions—economic market processes and the constitution—which grant different positions in society according to their specific institutional rules.Footnote 2 The constitutions of democratic systems grant their citizens rights without any preconditions, whereas their position within the economic market system is based on their success in this system [27]. Economic institutions can “generate substantial disparities among citizens in living standards and material welfare [14].”

The political institutions of the government are, on the one hand, confronted with and have to manage a socio-economic democratic system that guarantees the same rights to each individual without any preconditions, and on the other hand, with an economic system in which individual success is based mainly on individual performance. Society and its government have to find a way to balance the trade-off between these two principles to avoid political tensions between social groups and households, because of the trade-off between the conflicting principles of society’s democratic institutions and those of the economic market system: “At some points along the way, society confronts choices that offer somewhat more equality at the expense of efficiency or somewhat more efficiency at the expense of equality. In the idiom of the economist, a trade-off emerges between equality and efficiency [14].” Political projects such as the German Energiewende can be implemented more easily if social justice is taken into account, i.e. the distribution of the material welfare of society [26].

Hence, we can summarize that Gordon’s trade-off is the result of the relations between two competing institutions (the democratic system and the economic market system). This competition is confirmed by Stiglitz, who illustrates that these conflicts arising from the trade-off are not the “result of the forces of nature, of abstract forces. [They are] the result of government policies that shape and direct the forces of technology and markets and broader societal forces [36].” In other words, Gordon’s trade-off is politically shapeable by the institutions of society and has to be analysed so that this management process can avoid mismanagement on the basis of flawed data.

The need for such an analysis is also stressed by Acemoglu and Robinson [1], who argue “that economic analysis needs to identify, theoretically and empirically, conditions under which politics and economics run into conflict, and then evaluate policy proposals taking this conflict and the potential backlashes it creates into account [2].” These conflicts could endanger policy conceptions such as the German energy transition [13].

Our analysis tries to reveal societal obstacles in the socio-economic conditions of society which have to be addressed in transition processes and will show the necessity of political discourse concerning Gordon’s trade-off, because transition processes are not only technical problems but increasingly also socio-economic problems that have to be solved. No one in society can escape from these unsolved problems. Hence, we will analyse Gordon’s trade-off in the context of Thurow’s theory of public goods.

Thurow—distribution of public goods

Private and public goods

The idea of public goods was developed in 1954 by Samuelson in his paper “The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure” [23]. He explains the characteristics of a public good: “that each individual's consumption of such a good leads to no subtraction from any other individual's consumption of that good [23].” Public goods “can be enjoyed by everyone and from which no one can be excluded [24].” Hence, we can classify the private and public goods consumed by households [10] and needed for the well-being of households [17] into four major categories [10] (Table 1).

Table 1 Classification of goods

In the case of private goods, the use of such a good by one consumer excludes other consumers from consuming it (i.e. food). In contrast, a dike is a pure public good, because everyone behind it is protected. A club good [11, 28] refers to, for instance, the use of a gym. If the monthly fee is paid, everyone in the gym may use the equipment. A congested road is an impure public good—no one can be excluded from the use of the road, but there will be rivalry in using the road in the case of congestion [17].

Thurow’s public good approach

Income distribution

The distribution of income was already interpreted as a pure public good by Thurow in 1971 [39], because every individual is confronted with the same distribution of income. No individual can be excluded from the advantages and disadvantages of a given distribution of income, and there is also non-rivalry in the consumption of the advantages and disadvantages [37, 40] of a given distribution of income [39]. Every individual is confronted with the same distribution of income, because as Joseph Stiglitz explains: “Widely unequal societies do not function efficiently and their economies are neither stable nor sustainable … there comes a point when inequality spirals into economic dysfunction for the whole society [37].” Everyone needs a functioning society to sustain their social position [37]. That is to say, the distribution of income is a pure public good [39] which sustains the functioning of society. It functions like a dike to stabilize the socio-economic system.

Energy distribution

We will enlarge Thurow’s approach of a public good by interpreting not only the income distribution of German households but also the distribution of their energy expenses as a public good, because the participation of all households in the energy system is an important factor in the success of any country’s economy. The energy system is a dike for the socio-economic system which needs a competitive infrastructure. We therefore also interpreted the performance of the energy system as a public good for society, because no individual can be excluded from the advantages or disadvantages of the energy system and there is also non-rivalry in the consumption of the advantages or disadvantages of the energy system.

Hence, we will expand Thurow’s idea of a pure public good by including household energy consumption as a parameter for the quality of the German energy system. In the following, the distribution of the two public goods—income and energy system—will be analysed with the Atkinson index on the basis of the German household expenditure survey (EVS) database.

Methods

Atkinson index

The index is based on social theories [5] and regards society as “a cooperative project for the mutual [5]” benefit of all members of society.

The Atkinson index is a normative distribution measure. The index is based on a social welfare function, which implies diminishing marginal utility of income [5, 15]. The index thereby assumes additive social welfare, which is the sum of the individual utility of society members. This concept is based on utilitarian individual philosophy [15]. In this philosophy, the welfare of the other members of society is not part of the individual utility function [5]: Each individual simply maximizes his own utility and does not care about the other individuals. The welfare of the individual is measured independently of the income of other individuals [5, 15]. Hence, the level of possible energy consumption is based on the net income, and energy consumption is part of the social welfare function (SWF), as the following definition of the welfare function shows:

$$ \begin{array}{l}\begin{array}{l}\mathrm{S}\mathrm{W}\mathrm{F}={\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^nU\left(Y{\left(PC\Big(EC\right)}_i\right)},\ \mathrm{Y}=\mathrm{income},\ \mathrm{U}=\mathrm{utility}\ \mathrm{level},\ \mathrm{n}=\mathrm{number}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{households}\hfill \\ {}\kern20.5em \mathrm{E}\mathrm{C}=\mathrm{energy}\ \mathrm{consumption},\ \mathrm{P}\mathrm{C}=\mathrm{total}\ \mathrm{private}\ \mathrm{consumption}\hfill \end{array}\\ {}\kern6em \end{array} $$
(1)

In our theoretical approach (utilitarianism), an “outside observer” has to compare the individual members of society with each other. His instrument is the Atkinson index [15]. The Atkinson index calculates how society can assess the distribution of individual income and consumption expenditures between the different income classes of the social groups.Footnote 3 The index defines maximum inequality with 1 and maximum equality with 0 [26] and fulfils six mathematical axioms thus allowing it to measure inequality [26].

The Atkinson index has a specific feature for calculating distribution, namely the epsilon parameter ε [3, 4]. The epsilon parameter of Eq. (1) “defines how sensitively the Atkinson index should interpret inequalities [25].” The value ranges from zero to infinity. If society does not give any consideration to the distribution of income, then the value is zero (low inequality aversion). If society cares only about the lowest income group, then the value moves towards infinity (high inequality aversion).Footnote 4 “The larger epsilon is, the more strongly the Atkinson index reacts to inequalities [27].” Epsilon can therefore represent the inequality aversion of society and can be interpreted as the mathematical parameter of Gordon’s trade-off.

$$ \mathrm{Gordon}\hbox{'}\mathrm{s}\ \mathrm{Trade}\hbox{-} \mathrm{off}=\frac{\mathrm{Social}\ \mathrm{Equity}}{\mathrm{Economic}\ \mathrm{Efficiency}}=\mathrm{Inequality}\ \mathrm{Aversion}=\mathrm{Epsilon}\ \mathrm{Parameter}\ \mathrm{of}\ \mathrm{Atkinson}\ \mathrm{Index} $$
(2)

With the determination of the epsilon parameter, Gordon’s trade-off becomes measurable by the Atkinson index. Epsilon relates two institutions to each other: the societal trade-off between social equality based on a democratic constitution and market economic efficiency. Researchers, social stakeholders, or legislators can define the social meaning of inequality for socio-economic development and can define Gordon’s trade-off by the epsilon parameter. In a political discourse, society can develop a social view of its own understanding of how individuals treat and see each other in society which can also be expressed in the tax system. Epsilon confronts a society with its self-assessment as a just, fair society but also as an efficient market economy [25, 27].

We use the Atkinson index to determine the distributional effect of gross income, net income, private consumption, and energy expenditures [3]. The value of the Atkinson index is Thurow’s public good. It defines the distribution of income and energy expenditure and the shape of the dike which prevents economic and social distortions of the socio-economic system.

For our analysis, we use the modified Atkinson index (AIXtype) to analyse the inequality of these issues:

$$ {\mathrm{AIX}}_{\mathrm{type}}=1-{\left[{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{\left(\frac{X_{i, type}}{\overline{X_{\mathrm{type}}}}\right)}^{1-\varepsilon }}{f}_{i, type}\right]}^{\frac{1}{1-\varepsilon }},\kern0.5em X={Y}^G,{Y}^N,\ \mathrm{P}\mathrm{C},\ E,\ EK,\ EW,\ \mathrm{f}\mathrm{o}\mathrm{r}\ \varepsilon \ne 1. $$
(3)
$$ {\mathrm{AIX}}_{\mathrm{type}}=1- \exp \left[{\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^n{f}_{i, type}{ \log}_e\frac{X_{i, type}}{\overline{X_{\mathrm{type}}}}}\right],\ \mathrm{X}={\mathrm{Y}}^G,{\mathrm{Y}}^N,\ \mathrm{P}\mathrm{C},\ E,\ EK,\ EW,\ for\ \varepsilon =1 $$
(4)

\( {Y}_{i,\mathrm{type}}^G \) represents gross income of individuals, \( {Y}_{i, type}^N \) the net income of individuals, PC i,type consumption expenditure, E i,type energy consumption expenditure, EW i,type residential energy consumption expenditure, EK i,type car energy consumption expenditure in the i th income range (n sum of the income classes) in the household type (singles, singles with child(ren), couples, couples without child(ren), couples with child(ren)), f i,type is the proportion of the population in the particular household type with income in the i th income range, \( {\overline{X}}_{\mathrm{type}} \) is the mean household value for six income and expenditure issues (YG, YN, K, E, EK, EW) of the household types, and the epsilon parameter (ε) is the same for all groups.

Database—German household expenditure survey data

The German household expenditure survey (EVS) provides data sets on German economic life and the consumer behaviour of private households [34]. Every 5 years, the Federal Statistical Office questions a selection of German households (0.2% of all German households) about their income, expenditures, assets, consumer goods, and residential situation. The 2008 survey was the tenth survey, following surveys in 1962/63, 1969, 1973, 1978, 1983, 1988, 1993, 1998, 2003 [16, 35]. The EVS for 2008 was published in 2011 [31, 32]. The EVS for 2013 was not published in 2015. The EVS data sets provide an overview of the social conditions and socio-economic development of the population in Germany. The data sets are important not only for German social politics but also for all other socio-economic fields of politics [33].

Private households are the central object of investigation in the framework of the EVS.

Our analysis focuses on the following household types:

  1. 1.

    Single households

  2. 2.

    Single households with child(ren)

  3. 3.

    Couples

  4. 4.

    Couples without child(ren)

  5. 5.

    Couples with child(ren)

  6. 6.

    Other householdsFootnote 5

In our model, we consider all 39.409 million households which took part in the EVS survey, of which 15.537 million (30.1%) are single households, 1.339 million are single households with child(ren) (2.6%), and 17.381 million are couples (33.7%) living in one household, while 11.441 million of the couples households have no children (22.2%) and 5.940 million of the couples households have child(ren) (11.5%). We also consider the 5.152 million as other households (“sonstige Haushalte”).

The following table shows how German households are distributed among social groups and income groups. We analyse nine income classes as Table 2 shows.

Table 2 Distribution of households 2008

The table shows the distribution of the households over the nine income classes. The relatively largest group of all households (25.8%) is the income class € 2600–€ 3600, whereas within the single households, the income class € 900–€ 1300 has the largest relative proportion (22%). Within the single households with child(ren), the largest relative grouping (26.1%) is the income class € 1500–€ 2000, while couples have the biggest share (25.1%) in the income class of € 2600–€ 3600 and couples without children have the highest share (24.9%) in the income group of € 2600–€ 3600. Couples with child(ren) have the biggest share (28.4%) in the income group of € 3600–€ 5000. Nearly one third of the other households (29.3%) belong to the highest income group (€ 5000–€ 18,000).

Our paper measures the distribution of the public goods (income distribution and energy system) with the Atkinson index [3, 4].

In the first step, we analyse the first part of Gordon’s trade-off, i.e. the success of the household groups in the economic process, i.e. the income and consumption expenditures of the different household types.

Results

Real distribution

Disposable income of private households according to their social position

Our analysis is focused on five household types (single households, single households with child(ren), couples, couples without child(ren), couples with child(ren)), which are part of the group of all households. We analyse the real distribution of income, of consumption, and of energy expenses. In the first step, we analyse the dispersion of income [12, 1821, 38], consumption, and energy use. We define dispersion as the ratio of the income, consumption, and energy expenditures of the highest income group to the average household of the social group.

Monthly gross income

Couples without children achieved the highest average monthly gross income in 2008 (€ 9222), followed by other households (€ 9152) and couples (€ 9136). Singles and couples with child(ren) achieved nearly the same level of gross income (€ 9083, € 9037), whereas the gross income of singles with children in the highest income group is significantly lower (€ 7990).

The dispersion of the gross income varies significantly between the household types. We can identify three major groups: The highest dispersion is found in the single households group (4.14, 3.43). The second group consists of all couples and couples without children (1.97, 2.18). The income dispersion reaches its lowest value in the groups containing couples with child(ren) and other households (1.66, 1.67) (Table 3).

Table 3 Gross income 2008

Monthly net income

The monthly net income of private households also varies strongly with the social status of the main income recipient, as the following table shows (Table 4).

Table 4 Net income of private households in Germany 2008 according to their household type

Couples with children achieved the highest average monthly net income in 2008 (€ 4191), followed by couples (€ 3662), couples without child(ren) (€ 3387), and singles with and without child(ren) (€ 1943, € 1726). The dispersion of the net income varies significantly between the household types. Once again, the first group contains single households where the dispersion decreases from 4.09 to 3.3. The second group contains couples and couples without child(ren) (1.9, 2.1). They have a significantly lower dispersion than the single households. The income dispersion reaches its lowest value in the group containing couples with child(ren) and other households (1.6). The comparison of net and gross income shows that the German income tax system reduces the dispersion in this particular household type.

Expenditure of private households according to their social position

Monthly private consumption

Expenditure for private consumption also varies between the different household types, as the following Table 5 shows. The single households spend an average of € 1418 per month, singles with child(ren) € 1740, couples € 2757, couples without child(ren) € 2622, couples with child(ren) € 3017, and other households € 3142. The consumption expenditures increase with rising income without reaching a saturation point. The consumption dispersion is significantly lower than the income dispersion.

Table 5 Private consumption

The consumption dispersion of singles (2.35) and singles with child(ren) (2.12) is the highest of all households analysed, followed by couples (1.53, 1.62, 1.38) and other households (1.46). Their dispersion is much lower, and they have more similar consumption patterns than the single households.

In the following, we analyse the energy expenditures of the households.

Monthly energy consumption

The expenditures for energy consumption of the households will be analysed in more detail to obtain a picture of the real distribution of energy consumption in Germany. This includes car energy and residential energy expenditures and total energy expenditures as summarized in Table 6.

Table 6 Energy consumption—car, residential, and total

Energy expenses for cars

Energy expenses for cars include expenses for fuel and lubricants in the six social groups. The single households without and with children spend nearly the same amount (€ 50 and € 67, respectively) on car energy, whereas the couples without child(ren) spend on average € 111 and the couples with child(ren) and couples spend € 150 and € 124, respectively. The other households have on average the highest expenditures on car energy: € 160. With rising income, expenses for car energy increase continuously without reaching a saturation point. The dispersion of energy expenditure between the household types is significantly lower compared to income and overall consumption. In the case of car energy expenditure, it ranges from 1.18 to 1.94.

Residential energy expenditure

With respect to expenses for residential energy, all three couple household types have nearly the same expenditures for residential energy (€ 165, € 163, € 169). The single households with child(ren) (€ 119) have insignificantly higher residential energy expenditure than all single households (€ 93). The other households have the highest expenditures for residential energy, with an average of € 201. With rising income, expenses for residential energy increase continuously, reaching a saturation point before the highest income group only in the case of singles with child(ren). In the other household types, the residential energy expenditure increases without reaching a saturation point. Generally, the dispersion in the case of residential energy is lower than that of car energy. All household types show a dispersion between 1.17 and 1.65.

Total energy expenditure

When we now sum up the car and residential energy expenditures to calculate the total energy expenditures. We see that couples with child(ren) (€ 319) have nearly the highest energy expenditures followed by the other two couple household types (€ 274, € 289), whereas the two single household types have lower energy expenditures (€ 143, € 186). The other households have the highest energy expenditures: € 361.

With rising income, the total energy expenses increase and reach a saturation point before the highest income group only in the household type singles with child(ren). In the other household types, the total energy expenditures increase without reaching a saturation point before the highest income group.

Hence, the dispersion varies between households. Couple (1.18, 1.28, 1.33) and single households show a slightly higher dispersion (1.55, 1.75), whereas the other households have a dispersion similar to the couple households (1.32).

In the following, we also present the distribution of expenditures for another basic good: food and beverages. The comparison between food and energy enables us to classify the energy distribution results.

Food consumption

The expenditures for food and beverages differ among the households. But the dispersion of food expenditures is the lowest of all analysed types of consumption and income (Table 7).

Table 7 Food consumption

The single households spend on average €182 for food and beverages. These expenditures reach their saturation point at € 222 per month in the highest income class. The food consumption of singles with children increases on average by about € 100 to € 281 per month and reaches its saturation point in the income group of € 3600–5000 (€ 366) before the top income group, which consumes less (€ 357). The social group of couple households consumes on average food and beverage for € 400 a month, and this consumption reaches its highest value in the highest income group with € 486. Couples without children (€ 360, € 432) consume on average and in the top group less than all couples. Food and beverage consumption increases on average in the social group of couples with children to € 478 a month and in the top income group this rises to € 547. The social group of other households has the highest monthly food consumption with on average € 483 and in the top group € 603. The food consumption dispersion for other households (1.25) and single parents (1.27) is the highest of all households analysed, followed by couples (1.2, 1.2, 1.14). Couples with children have food consumption patterns that are more similar than the other households.

Our analysis shows how the household types’ heterogeneous levels of success in the economic system may be measured in income and consumption expenditures.

Discussion

In the following, we examine how the real distribution of expenses and income is perceived by the households against the background of differing levels of inequality aversion within society, i.e. how society assesses the distribution of income and expenditures against their normative perception of inequality.

Normative distribution

In the following, we examine how the real distribution of expenses and income is perceived by the households against the background of differing levels of inequality aversion within society, i.e. how society assesses the distribution of income and expenditures against their normative perception of inequality. In our analysis, the epsilon parameter of the Atkinson index ranges from 1 to 2.5, whereas (ε = 1, 1.5) represents a low inequality aversion of society and (ε = 2, 2.5) represents a high inequality aversion of German society.

Singles

In the case of the single households, the net income (0.149–0.299) is more equally distributed than the gross income (0.176–0.356). This illustrates the effectiveness of the German tax system in reducing some of the inequality of the German economic market system.

The consumption patterns of the singles (0.066–0.149) are distributed more equally between the households than the two income types.

In the case of energy consumption, the expenditures on residential energy (0.023–0.053) are nearly equally distributed between the households. On the other hand, the expenditures for car energy are more unequally distributed in this household group than the gross income (0.165–0.388). Residential energy expenditures are of central importance for the households irrespective of their income, whereas individual mobility (cars) is not necessarily required by all households. For the single households, the public transport system is an alternative. This explains why in the single households the car energy values of the Atkinson index are higher than the residential energy. Table 8 shows that “food” is the most equally distributed (0.006–0.018) item of the analysed data sample. As expected, food is the main basic good for single households.

Table 8 Atkinson index of single households

Singles with child(ren)

As in the household groups of all single households, the net income of single households with child(ren) is more equally distributed than the gross income. The data confirms that the German tax system evens out the inequalities of the economic market system to some extent. The gross income of single households with child(ren) is more unequally distributed (0.125–0.258) than the income of the group consisting of all single households. This is also valid for the net income.

We can also see that the distribution of private consumption (0.056–0.121) and of all energy expenditures (0.038–0.087) is more equal in this household type than car energy expenditures (0.106–0.262). Table 9 illustrates that also in this social group food consumption is the most equally distributed consumption issue.

Table 9 Atkinson index of single households with child(ren)

Couples

In the couple group, the gross income (0.138–0.323) is again more unequally distributed than the net income (0.118–0.277) due to the German tax system (Table 10).

Table 10 Atkinson index of all couples households

This is also valid for the consumption patterns (0.05–0.124) and energy expenditures (0.025–0.067). The residential energy expenditures (0.025–0.034) of this household group are again the most equally distributed issue in this household group. The results also show that car energy expenditures (0.047–0.139) are more unequally distributed than residential energy expenditures but more equally distributed than in the case of single households. Food consumption is distributed in the same way in the couple households (0.011–0.038) as in the single households with children.

Couples without child(ren)

In the case of the gross and net income, we see again that, because of the tax system, the net income (0.124–0.355) is more equally distributed than the gross income (0.150–0.355). We can assert that residential energy (0.017–0.041) is again the most equally distributed good. Private consumption (0.053–0.128) is distributed in a manner similar to car energy (0.057–0.148), and a little more unequally than energy expenditures.

The food consumption of the couple households with children (0.008–0.020) is more equally distributed than that of all couples. Table 11 also documents the basic need character of food consumption, because it is the most equally distributed good of these households.

Table 11 Atkinson index of couples without child(ren)

Couples with child(ren)

The effects of the German tax system as an instrument to reduce income inequality can also be confirmed by the analysis of the gross (0.104–0.267) and net income (0.091–0.227) of couples with children (Table 12).

Table 12 Atkinson index of couples with child(ren)

Private consumption in this household group is relatively equally distributed. But the results show that car energy expenditures are also equally distributed and we can see a clear contrast to the single households, where car energy expenditures are distributed very unequally. We can conclude from this that car energy expenditures are not necessarily an essential good for single households, but for the couples, especially for those with children, they are indispensable. In the households of couples with children, food consumption is also very equally distributed, and the Atkinson index (0.007–0.018) is a good indicator of that.

Other households

The final household type in our analysis is the group containing other households. This household group also confirms the effects of the German tax system, which reduces income inequality between the members of that household type (0.176–0.337 to 0.149–0.326).

Table 13 shows that the inequality assessed by the modified Atkinson index increases with rising epsilon irrespective of which issue is analysed. The energy expenditures (0.048–0.133) of that group are more equally distributed than the overall private consumption (0.065–0.167). The residential energy expenditures (0.024–0.069) are more equally distributed than the car energy expenditures (0.030–0.129). Food consumption is more unequally distributed in the group of all other households than in the other household groups. The values of the Atkinson index (0.025–0.065) are near the values of the residential energy. The other households group, which includes, for example, parents-in-law, children over 18 and groups sharing an apartment, is more heterogeneous than the single and couple households, which explains the higher Atkinson index.

Table 13 Atkinson index of other households

Conclusions

Summary

We can therefore summarize that the household group of couples with child(ren) is the most homogeneous group and that their net income is more equally distributed than their gross income. Private consumption is more equally distributed than both income types, and energy services are distributed almost equally between the household types. However, the single households are the most heterogeneous household group and show a more differentiated distribution picture than the couple households. In both single household types, the German tax system significantly reduces the inequality between households. In the case of epsilon 2.5—representing a high inequality aversion—the German tax system reduces the Atkinson index of single households from 0.356 to 0.299. But also in the single households, private consumption is more equally distributed than income, and energy expenditures are still the most equally distributed expenditure type (0.055–0.125). What is striking in this group is the fact that car energy expenditures are the most unevenly distributed expenditure type. We have seen that energy expenditures are more equally distributed than private consumption and income types. The nearly equal distribution of energy expenditures confirms Smil’s assumption that energy is the universal currency [30] for people’s welfare and can be seen as an indicator of the basic needs of the households, whereby “basic” means something different in different countries—for Germany basic needs means an energy consumption which offers social participation. These basic energy needs are to a large extent, but not completely, independent of people’s income situation.

This means that the lower income groups have to spend a very high percentage of their income on energy services compared to the higher income groups (Table 14). Households with a net income lower than € 900 are divided into two major groups. The singles in this income group spend between 11.9 and 13.6% of their income on energy services. They spend between 3 and 4 basis points more than the average household in this social group and nearly 10 basis points more than the highest income group.

Table 14 Energy consumption of private households in relation to net income* Germany 2008 according to their social position—in %

However, we get a different picture in the social group of couples households: the couple households of the income group <€ 900 spend more than 25% of their net income on energy services. Rising energy prices would affect these households directly. In this case, they would have to rearrange the expenditures in their household budgets. They would have to reduce other expenditures to maintain their use of energy services at its current level; otherwise, they would lose access to modern energy services which are “crucial to human well-being and to a country’s economic development” as the IEA stated. There is a danger that these households will be confronted with energy poverty, which can be defined as a “condition wherein a household is unable to access energy services [8]” at its accustomed level, and so there is a growing need for energy governance. Energy poverty constitutes an infringement of the sustainability concept: environmental, economic, and social targets have to be balanced in the transition to a low-carbon economy.

Outlook

Our analysis reveals that energy poverty and the socio-economic conditions of society and its energy sector have to be addressed in transition processes to a sustainable society and have to be at the centre of any energy transition process and its political discourse. The analysis of Gordon’s trade-off shows that transition processes such as the German Energiewende are not only technical problems but increasingly also socio-economic problems that have to be solved by energy governance [6], and because of Thurow’s public good approach, no one in society can escape from the unsolved problems of Gordon’s trade-off.

The analysis using the Atkinson index can reveal deeper insights into the self-perception of society and the conception of justice and equality, which are central pillars of a sustainable society. The epsilon parameter thereby enables us to parameterize this perception and conception in measuring the distribution of consumption and income. Our analysis is necessary, because every economic and political reform has distributional effects. If politicians do not consider these effects (energy poverty), they can endanger the total reform of the energy sector (Energiewende), because people will turn away from the goals of the reform [1, 9]. Acceptance of reforms such as the German Energiewende will thus decline.

The transformation of current energy systems into sustainable systems is on the agenda of all European countries (EU climate policy). Therefore, such a transformation could (and probably will) also lead to rising electricity prices, placing an above-average strain on the lowest income groups. Moreover, this regressive effect will appear in all categories of expenditure if prices increase, no matter whether this is caused by political decisions or market forces.

Our index can also be applied to other countries with respect to energy and other household expenditures, if the respective national statistical office provides the necessary household survey data for the analysis. Our index can then provide decision makers and institutions with information on how (un)equally the costs of transformation processes are distributed between the different income groups. We used energy in our analysis because it is one of the basic needs, and the energy sector is at the centre of the German transformation process: the Energiewende. Energy poverty caused by the Energiewende—as a synonym for a lack of societal participation in the transformation process, at least in highly developed countries—can endanger the whole transformation process. Political strategies to strengthen participation should therefore focus on the regressive effect of high energy prices.

Decision makers and political institutions can decide in a public discourse which categories of expenditures should be analysed and which are more important and relevant to justify political interventions to reduce the inequality caused by rising prices.

The index could also deliver information about the differences in income distribution in EU countries. For this analysis, we need reliable and comparable statistical data for the whole of Europe. However, in our view, two important political obstacles are looming: Firstly, it is difficult enough to find common political ground in domestic policy between the different political actors and interest groups in order to distribute the costs of national transformation policies. Secondly, this challenge is raised to a completely different level if wealth is to be redistributed between EU states (Euro crisis, Greek debt crisis) to a much larger extent than is the case today (EU Regional Fund, Structural Fund etc.).

To summarize, our concept has both a detection (revealing the implicit preferences) and potentially also an orientation function (defining explicit societal preferences with respect to the degree of homogeneity of a society).

Notes

  1. Kermit Gordon (1916–1976) was Director of the United States Bureau of the Budget (now the Office of Management and Budget) (December 28, 1962–June 1, 1965) during the administration of Lyndon Johnson, and he was also the president of the Brookings Institution. He oversaw the creation of the first budgets for Johnson’s Great Society domestic agenda. Gordon was a member of the Council of Economic Advisors, 1961–1962.

  2. For our analysis, we take up the definition of an institution offered by Rawls. Institutions in Rawls’s sense are the constitution, economic and social conditions, freedom of thought, freedom of conscience, economic markets with competition, and private property [22].

  3. Nicholas Barr shows that the Gini coefficient has two disadvantages for measuring inequality, which are avoided by the Atkinson index [5]. The Gini coefficient is not an unambiguous measure because, as Hauser and Barr have shown, different distributions can lead to the same Gini coefficient [13, 52]. Hence, we decided to use the Atkinson index to estimate the distributional effects of increasing energy prices [27].

  4. This analytical view is based on Rawls’ theory of justice, where inequality is determined by the “position of the least advantaged members of society. Where epsilon lies between these extremes depends on the importance attached to redistribution towards the bottom [3].”

  5. Other households include, e.g. parents-in-law, children over 18, and groups sharing an apartment.

References

  1. Acemoglu D, Robinson J (2012) Why nations fail: the origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Crown Business, New York

    Google Scholar 

  2. Acemoglu D, Robinson JA (2013) Economics versus Politics: Pitfalls of Policy Advice. J Econ Perspect 2, 173–192, doi:10.1257/jep.27.2.173

  3. Atkinson AB (1983) The economics of inequality. Clarendon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  4. Atkinson AB (1970) On the measurement of inequality. J Econ Theory 2:244–263

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  5. Barr N (1993) The economics of the welfare state. Stanford University Press, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  6. Bazilian M, Nakhooda S, Van De Graaf T (2014) Energy governance and poverty. Energy Research & Social Science 1:217–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Bell D (1996 (1976)) The cultural contradictions of capitalism. Basic Books, New York

  8. Bouzarovski S, Petrova S, Sarlamanov R (2012) Energy poverty policies in the EU: a critical perspective. Energy Policy 49:76–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Braunberger G (2013) Ökonomen verstehen zu wenig von Politik (unter unterschätzen Verteilungsthemen). In: FAZ blogs (ed) Das Fazit-wirtschaftsblog. FAZ, Frankfurt/M

  10. Brümmerhoff D (2007) Finanzwissenschaft. Oldenbourg Verlag, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  11. Buchanan JM (1965) An economic theory of clubs. Economica 32:1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Edmond C, Veldkamp L (2009) Income dispersion and counter-cyclical markups. J Monet Econ 56:791–804

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. German Federal Ministry of Economics and Technology (Bmwi) (2012) Germany’s new energy policy. BMWI, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  14. Gordon K (1975) Foreword. In: Okun AM (ed) Equality and efficiency: the big tradeoff. The Brookings Institution, Washington D.C

    Google Scholar 

  15. Hauser R (1996) Zur Messung individueller Wohlfahrt und ihrer Verteilung. In: Chlumsky J, Wiegert R (eds) Wohlfahrtsmessung - Aufgabe der Statistik im gesellschaftlichen Wandel. Statistisches Bundesamt, Wiesbaden, pp 13–38

    Google Scholar 

  16. Jung S (2001) Privater Verbrauch in Deutschland. DUV, Wiesbaden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  17. Kaul I, Grunberg I, Stern MA (1999) Global public goods. UNDP, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  18. Metwally MM, Jensen RC (1973) A note on the measurement of regional income dispersion. Econ Dev Cult Chang 22:135–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Mulas-Granados C, Sanz I (2008) The dispersion of technology and income in Europe: evolution and mutual relationship across regions. Res Policy 37:836–848

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Park J (2006) Dispersion of human capital and economic growth. J Macroecon 28:520–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Ramos HM, Sordo MA (2003) Dispersion measures and dispersive orderings. Statistics & Probability Letters 61:123–131

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  22. Rawls J (1971) A theory of justice. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  23. Samuelson PA (1954) The pure theory of public expenditure. Rev Econ Stat 36:387–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Samuelson PA, Nordhaus WD (2010) Economics. McGraw-Hill Education (Asia), New York

    Google Scholar 

  25. Schlör H, Fischer W, Hake J-F (2012) Measuring social welfare, energy and inequality in Germany. Appl Energy 97:135–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Schlör H, Fischer W, Hake J-F (2012) Social welfare, income, consumption, energy, and the inequality aversion of society—a case study from Germany. J Eur Econ 11:356–377

    Google Scholar 

  27. Schlör H, Fischer W, Hake J-F (2013) Sustainable development, justice and the Atkinson index: measuring the distributional effects of the German energy transition (in press). Applied Energy 112:1493-1499

  28. Scotchmer S (2008) Clubs. In: Durlauf SN, Blume LE (eds) The new Palgrave dictionary of economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke

    Google Scholar 

  29. Sen A (1973) On economic inequality. Norton, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  30. Smil V (1994) Energy in world history. Westview, Boulder

    Google Scholar 

  31. Bundesamt S (2011) Einkommens- und Verbrauchsstichprobe - Einkommensverteilung in Deutschland 2008. Wirtschaftsrechnungen, Wiesbaden

    Google Scholar 

  32. Bundesamt S (2011) Einkommens- und Verbrauchsstichprobe -Einnahmen und Ausgaben privater Haushalte 2008. Wirtschaftsrechnungen, Wiesbaden

    Google Scholar 

  33. Statistisches Bundesamt (2013) Wirtschaftsrechnungen Einkommens- und Verbrauchsstichprobe Aufgabe, Methode und Durchführung. Fachserie Wirtschaftsrechnungen Fachserie 15, Heft 7

  34. Statistisches Bundesamt (Federal Statistical Office) (2005) Einkommens- und Verbrauchsstichprobe - Aufgabe, Methode und Durchführung der EVS. Fachserie Wirtschaftsrechnungen 15, Heft 7

  35. Statistisches Bundesamt (Federal Statistical Office) (2005) Einkommens- und Verbrauchsstichprobe - Einnahmen und Ausgaben privater Haushalte 2003. Fachserie Wirtschaftsrechnungen 15, Reihe 1

  36. Stiglitz J (2012) Price of inequality. Norton, London

    Google Scholar 

  37. Stiglitz JE (2012) The 1 percent’s problem. Vanity Fair, London

    Google Scholar 

  38. Theil H, Fiebig DG (1986) The measurement of income and price dispersion in cross-country demand analysis. Econ Lett 22:391–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Thurow LC (1971) The income distribution as a pure public good. Q J Econ 85:327–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Wilkinson R, Pickett K (2010) The spirit level. Why equality is better for everyone. Penguin, London

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors’ contributions

HS initiated the research idea of analyzing Gordon’s trade-off and developed the Atkinson model based on EVS data. HS and WF designed and organized all the research for this study. WF reviewed the theory of public goods. JFH had a leading role in the literature review and the analysis of the real distribution of the EVS data. All the authors contributed to the conclusion and the outlook of the study. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Holger Schlör.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Schlör, H., Fischer, W. & Hake, JF. Analysing Gordon’s trade-off by adapting Thurow’s approach of pure public good to the German energy sector. Energ Sustain Soc 6, 34 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13705-016-0100-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s13705-016-0100-1

Keywords